|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
GMGMGMGMGMGxcMGMGMGM |
|
|
|
|
|
|
Poverty
|
Poverty Dictionary
Definition
|
|
Definition
|
- The state of being poor; lack
of the means of providing material
needs or comforts.
- Deficiency in amount; scantiness:
the poverty of feeling that reduced
her soul (Scott Turow).
- Unproductiveness; infertility:
the poverty of the soil.
- Renunciation made by a member
of a religious order of the right
to own property
|
|
Source and
Copy Right Information:
Dictionary
definition of Poverty.
The American Heritage® Dictionary
of the English Language, Fourth Edition
Copyright © 2004, 2000 by
Houghton Mifflin Company. Published
by Houghton Mifflin Company. All rights
reserved.
More
from
Dictionary
|
|
|
Poverty: Barron's
Business Terms
|
|
Definition
|
1. Relative measure within a society,
being the state of having income and/or
wealth so low as to be unable to maintain
what is considered a minimum
Standard of Living.
2. In absolute terms, having income
and/or wealth too low to maintain life
and health at a
Subsistence level.
|
|
Source and
Copy Right Information:
Business
Terms information about Poverty.
Dictionary of Finance
and Investment Terms. Copyright
© 2006 by
Barron's Educational Series, Inc.
All rights reserved.
More
from
Finance and Investment Terms.
|
|
|
Poverty: Houghton
Mifflin Company
|
|
Definition
|
- The condition of being extremely
poor:
beggary,
destitution,
impecuniosity,
impecuniousness,
impoverishment,
indigence,
need,
neediness,
pennilessness,
penuriousness,
penury,
privation,
want. See
rich/poor.
- The condition or fact of being
deficient:
defect,
deficiency,
deficit,
inadequacy,
insufficiency,
lack,
paucity,
scantiness,
scantness,
scarceness,
scarcity,
shortage,
shortcoming,
shortfall,
underage1. See
excess/insufficiency/enough.
|
|
Source and
Copy Right Information:
Thesaurus
synonyms of poverty.
The New Dictionary of Cultural Literacy,
Third Edition Edited by E.D. Hirsch,
Jr., Joseph F. Kett, and James Trefil.
Copyright © 2002 by
Houghton Mifflin Company. Published
by Houghton Mifflin. All rights reserved.
More
from
Economics
|
|
|
|
|
|
Poverty Definition
: Word Net
|
|
Definition
|
Poverty is the state of having
little or no money and few or no material
possessions
|
|
Source and
Copy Right Information:
WordNet
information about Pverty.
WordNet 1.7.1 Copyright © 2001
by Princeton University. All rights
reserved.
More
from
WordNet
|
|
|
Poverty : Wikipedia
[Webmaster's Choice]
|
|
Definition
and Explanation |
Poverty is understood in many
senses. The main understandings of the
term include:
-
Descriptions of material need, typically
including the necessities of daily
living, like (food,
clothing, and
shelter). Poverty in this sense
may be understood as the deprivation
of essential goods and services.
-
Describing a lack of sufficient
income and
wealth. The meaning of "sufficient"
varies widely across the different
political and
economic parts of the world.
-
Descriptions of social need, such
as
social exclusion, dependency,
and the ability to participate in
society. This would include
education and
information. Social exclusion
is usually distinguished from poverty,
as it encompasses political and
moral issues, and is not restrained
to the sphere of economics.
Measuring poverty
Although the most severe poverty is
in the developing world, there is evidence
of poverty in every region. In developed
countries, this condition results in
wandering
homeless people and poor suburbs
and
ghettos. Poverty may be seen as
the collective condition of poor people,
or of poor groups, and in this sense
entire
nation-states are sometimes regarded
as poor. To avoid stigma these nations
are usually called
developing nations.
When measured, poverty may be
absolute or
relative poverty. Absolute poverty
refers to a set standard which is consistent
over time and between countries. An
example of an absolute measurement would
be the percentage of the population
eating less food than is required to
sustain the human body (approximately
2000-2500
kilocalories per day).
The
World Bank defines
extreme poverty as living on
less than US$ (PPP)
1 per day, and moderate poverty
as less than $2 a day. It has been estimated
that in 2001, 1.1 billion people had
consumption levels below $1 a day and
2.7 billion lived on less than $2 a
day. The proportion of the
developing world's population living
in extreme economic poverty has fallen
from 28 percent in 1990 to 21 percent
in 2001. Much of the improvement has
occurred in East and South Asia. In
Sub-Saharan Africa GDP/capita shrank
with 14 percent and extreme poverty
increased from 41 percent in 1981 to
46 percent in 2001. Other regions have
seen little or no change. In the early
1990s the transition economies of Europe
and Central Asia experienced a sharp
drop in income. Poverty rates rose to
6 percent at the end of the decade before
beginning to recede. There are various
criticisms of these measurements.
Other indicators of absolute poverty
are also improving.
Life expectancy has greatly increased
in the developing world since
WWII and is starting to close the
gap to the developed world where the
improvement has been smaller. Even in
Sub-Saharan Africa, the least developed
region, life expectancy increased from
30 years before World War II to a peak
of about 50 years before the HIV pandemic
and other diseases started to force
it down to the current level of 47 years.
Child mortality has decreased in
every developing region of the world
. The proportion of the world's population
living in countries where per-capita
food supplies are less than 2,200
calories (9,200
kilojoules) per day decreased from
56% in the mid-1960s to below 10% by
the 1990s. Between 1950 and 1999, global
literacy increased from 52% to 81% of
the world. Women made up much of the
gap: Female literacy as a percentage
of male literacy has increased from
59% in 1970 to 80% in 2000. The percentage
of children not in the labor force has
also risen to over 90% in 2000 from
76% in 1960. There are similar trends
for electric power, cars, radios, and
telephones per capita, as well as the
proportion of the population with access
to clean water.
Relative poverty views poverty as socially
defined and dependent on
social context. In this case, the
number of people counted as poor could
increase while their income rise. A
relative measurement would be to compare
the total wealth of the poorest one-third
of the population with the total wealth
of richest 1% of the population. There
are several different
income inequality metrics, one example
is the
Gini coefficient.
In many developed countries the official
definition of poverty used for statistical
purposes is based on relative income.
As such many critics argue that poverty
statistics measure inequality rather
than material deprivation or hardship.
For instance, according to the U.S.
Census Bureau, 46% of those in "poverty"
in the U.S. own their own home (with
the average poor person's home having
three bedrooms, with one and a half
baths, and a garage). Furthermore, the
measurements are usually based on a
person's yearly income and frequently
take no account of total wealth. The
main
poverty line used in the
OECD and the
European Union is based on "economic
distance", a level of income set at
50% of the median household income.
The US poverty line is more arbitrary.
It was created in 1963-64 and was based
on the dollar costs of the U.S. Department
of Agriculture's "economy food plan"
multiplied by a factor of three. The
multiplier was based on research showing
that food costs then accounted for about
one third of the total money income.
This one-time calculation has since
been annually updated for inflation.
Income inequality for the world
as a whole may be diminishing.
Even if poverty may be lessening for
the world as a whole, it continues to
be an enormous problem:
-
One third of deaths - some 18 million
people a year or 50,000 per day
- are due to poverty-related causes.
That's 270 million people since
1990, the majority women and children,
roughly equal to the population
of the US.
-
Every year nearly 11 million children
die before their fifth birthday.
|
|
Source and
Copy Right Information:
Wikipedia
information about Poverty.
This article is licensed under
the
GNU Free Documentation License.
It uses material from the
Wikipedia article "Poverty".
More
from
Wikipedia
|
|
|
|
Income Inequality: From
Wikipedia
|
|
Income Inequality
: Wikipedia [Webmaster's Choice]
|
|
Income Inequality
Metrics |
Income
inequality metrics or
income distribution metrics
are techniques used by economists to
measure the distribution of income among
members of a society. In particular
these techniques are used to measure
the inequality, or equality of income
within an economy. These techniques
are typically categorized as either
absolute measures or relative measures.
Absolute income criteria
Absolute measures define a minimum standard,
then calculate the number (or percent)
of individuals below this threshold.
These methods are most useful when determining
the amount of
poverty in a society. Examples include:
-
Poverty line - This is a
measure of the level of income necessary
to subsist in a society. It varies
from place to place and from time
to time, depending on the cost of
living and people's expectations.
It is usually defined by governments
and calculated as that level of
income at which a household will
devote two thirds (to three quarters)
of its income to basic necessities
such as food, water, shelter, and
clothing.
-
Poverty index - This index
was developed by
Amartya Sen. It takes into account
both the number of poor and the
extent of their poverty. Sen defined
the index as:
-
I = (P/N)(B
− A)/A
where:
-
P = number of people below
the poverty line
-
N = total number of people
in society
-
B = poverty line income
-
A = average income of those
people below the poverty line
Relative income criteria
Relative income measures compare the
income of one individual (or group)
with the income of another individual
(or group). These measures are most
useful when analyzing the scope and
distribution of income inequality. Examples
include:
-
Percentile distributions
- One
percentile is compared to another.
For example, it might be determined
that the income of the top ten-percentile
is only slightly more than the bottom
forty-percentile. Or it might be
determined that the top quartile
earns 45% of the society's income
while the bottom quartile has 10%
of society's income. The
interquartile range is a standard
percentile range from 25% to 75%.
-
Lorenz curve - This is a
graphic device used to display the
relative inequality in a distribution
of income values. A society's total
income is ordered according to income
level and the cumulative total graphed.
-
Gini coefficient - This
is a summary statistic used to quantify
the extent of income inequality
depicted in a particular Lorenz
curve.
-
Robin Hood index - Mathematically
related to the Gini coefficient,
it measures the portion of the total
income that would have to be redistributed
in order for there to be perfect
equality.
-
Theil index - This is also
a summary statistic used to measure
income inequality, based on
information entropy. It is similar
to, but less commonly used than
the Gini coefficient.
-
Standard deviation of income
- This measures income dispersion
by assessing the squared variance
from the mean. This metric is seldom
seen, its use limited to occasional
reference in academic journals.
-
Relative poverty line - This
is a measure of the number or proportion
of people or households whose level
of income is less than some given
fraction of typical incomes. This
form of poverty measurement tends
to concentrate concern on the bottom
half of the income distribution
and pay less attention to ineqalities
in the top half. See
poverty line for details.
|
|
Source and
Copy Right Information:
Wikipedia
information about Inequality.
This article is licensed under
the
GNU Free Documentation License.
It uses material from the
Wikipedia article "Income inequality
metrics".
More from
Wikipedia
|
|
|
Income Inequality
: Wikipedia
|
|
Other Topics Related to Income Inequality
|
Defining income
Both of the above measures use income
as the basis for evaluating poverty.
However, 'income' is here understood
different to a common understanding:
It means the total amount of goods and
services that a person receives, and
thus there is not necessarily money
or cash involved. If a poor subsistence
farmer in Uganda grows her own grain
it will count as income. Services like
public health and education are also
counted in. Often expenditure or consumption
(which is the same in an economic sense)
is used to measure income. The
World Bank uses the so-called
living standard
measurement surveys (LSMS)
to measure income. These consist of
questionnaires with 200+ questions.
Surveys have been completed in most
developing countries.
Criticisms of income inequality metrics
-
It is not clear how income should
be defined. Should it include
capital gains, imputed house
rents from home ownership, and gifts?
If these income sources are ignored
(as they often are), how might this
bias the analysis? How should non-paid
work (such as parental childcare)
be handled? Wealth or consumption
may be more appropriate measures
in some situations. Broader
metrics of human well-being
might be useful.
-
Should the basic unit of measurement
be households or individuals? The
Gini value for households is always
lower than for individuals because
of income pooling and intra-family
transfers. The metrics will be biased
either upward or downward depending
on which unit of measurement is
used.
-
These income inequality metrics
ignore life cycle effects. In most
Western societies, an individual
tends to start life with little
or no income, gradually increase
income till about age 50, after
which incomes will decline, eventually
becoming negative. This will have
the effect of significantly overstating
inequality. It has been estimated
(by A.S. Blinder in The Decomposition
of Inequality, MIT press) that
30% of measured income inequality
is due to the inequality an individual
experiences as they go through the
various stages of life.
-
Should real or nominal income distributions
be used? What effect will inflation
have on absolute measures? Do some
groups (eg., pensioners) feel the
effect of inflation more than others?
-
How do we allocate the benefits
of government spending? How does
the existence of a social security
safety net influence the definition
of absolute measures of poverty.
Do government programs support some
income groups more than others?
-
Income inequality metrics are seldom
used to quantify and examine the
causes of income inequality. Some
alleged causes include: life cycle
effects (age), inherited characteristics
(IQ, talent), willingness to take
chances (risk aversion), the leisure/industriousness
choice, inherited wealth, economic
circumstances, education and training,
discrimination, and market imperfections.
These criticisms help to understand
the problems caused by the improper
use of inequality measures. However,
they do not render inequality coefficients
invalid. If inequality measures are
computed in a well explained and
consistent way, they can provide
a good tool for quantitative comparisons
of inequalities at least within a research
project.
Benefits and costs associated with
Income inequality
In many capitalist countries there undeniably
is a marked level of inequality in income
distribution. This could be defined
as having a gini coefficient of over
.25 - but even that is a generous allowance
of inequity. Whilst if all resources
were put toward creating a more equitable
distribution of income, relative equality,
or a least a 'fairer' distribution could
be achieved. However, this is very rarely
done, and there are economic reasons
for this.
Optimal Level of Inequality
In their
study for the World Institute for Development
Economics Research, Giovanni Andrea
Cornia and Julius Court (2001) reach
policy conclusions as to the optimal
distribution of wealth. The authors
recommend to pursue moderation also
as to the distribution of wealth and
particularly to avoid the extremes.
Both very high egalitarianism and very
high inequality cause slow growth. Extreme
egalitarianism leads to incentive-traps,
free-riding, high operation costs and
corruption in the redistribution system,
all reducing a country's growth potential.
[see
Gini-Growth curve here]
However also extreme inequality diminishes
growth potential through the erosion
of social cohesion, increasing social
unrest and social conflict causing uncertainty
of property rights. Therefore public
policy should target an 'efficient inequality
range'. The authors claim that such
efficiency range roughly lies between
the values of the Gini coefficients
of 25 (the inequality value of a typical
Northern European country) and 40 (that
of countries such as China and the USA).
The precise shape of the inequality-growth
relationship depicted in the Chart obviously
varies across countries depending upon
their resource endowment, history, remaining
levels of absolute poverty and available
stock of social programs, as well as
on the distribution of physical and
human capital.
|
|
Source and
Copy Right Information:
Wikipedia
information about Inequality.
This article is licensed under
the
GNU Free Documentation License.
It uses material from the
Wikipedia article "Income inequality
metrics".
More
from
Wikipedia
|
|
|
|
|